[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions >> FDA & Ors, R (on the application of) v Secretary of State for Work and Pensions & Anor [2012] EWCA Civ 332 (20 March 2012) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWCA/Civ/2012/332.html Cite as: [2012] EWCA Civ 332, [2012] 3 All ER 301, [2012] Pens LR 215, [2012] WLR(D) 95, [2013] 1 WLR 444 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [View ICLR summary: [2012] WLR(D) 95] [Buy ICLR report: [2013] 1 WLR 444] [Help]
ON APPEAL FROM THE HIGH COURT OF JUSTICE
QUEEN'S BENCH DIVISION, ADMINISTRATIVE COURT
Lord Justice Elias, Mr Justice McCombe and Mr Justice Sales
Case Nos CO/3570/2011 and CO/4082/2011
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
THE VICE-PRESIDENT OF THE COURT OF APPEAL (CIVIL DIVISION)
and
LORD JUSTICE SULLIVAN
____________________
The Queen on the application of (1) FDA (2) PROSPECT (3) CIVIL SERVICE PENSIONERS' ALLIANCE (4) JAMES DUNLOP (5) GMB (6) NATIONAL UNION OF TEACHERS (7) VALERIE PIPER (8) FIRE BRIGADES UNION (9) NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF SCHOOLMASTERS UNION OF WOMEN TEACHERS (10) PUBLIC AND COMMERCIAL SERVICES UNION (11) PRISON OFFICERS ASSOCIATION |
Appellants |
|
- and - |
||
THE SECRETARY OF STATE FOR WORK AND PENSIONS HER MAJESTY'S TREASURY |
Respondents |
____________________
Mr Nigel Giffin QC and Mr Christopher Knight (instructed by Messrs Thompsons) for the seventh to eleventh appellants
Mr James Eadie QC, Mr Clive Sheldon QC and Ms Amy Rogers (instructed by The Treasury Solicitor) for the respondents
Hearing dates: 20 and 21 February 2012
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
The Master of the Rolls:
A summary of the issues
The two indices, RPI and CPI
The factual background
'So from next year, with the exception of the State pension and pension credit, we will switch to a system where we up-rate benefits, tax credits, and public service pensions in line with consumer prices rather than retail prices. [CPI] not only reflects everyday prices better, but it is of course now the inflation measure targeted by the Bank of England. This will save over £6 billion a year by the end of the Parliament. I believe that this is a fairer approach than a benefits freeze.'
'As well as the considerable savings that could be made by the switch from the RPI to the CPI, the Secretary of State considered that the switch would have other advantages: (a) the fact that CPI was already the headline measure for price inflation, used by the Bank of England, and so a more widely recognised measure of the general level of prices; and (b) our view that the CPI was more suitable than the RPI as a measure of inflation for benefit claimants, as it excludes mortgage interest payments but includes all pensioner households.'
'it was recognised that no index can perfectly capture everyone's experience of inflation,.. it was considered [by the Secretary of State] that a single index should be used for up-rating and the CPI was considered to be the most appropriate.'
'The policy imperative of a move to indexation by the CPI such as we had considered in 2009 became particularly urgent in early to mid 2010 given the need to ensure long-term fiscal savings ...'.
' [T]here is a body of empirical evidence that people do substitute and that the geometric mean is an appropriate reflection of that. In Australia in 2009 a study found that, in the overwhelming majority of cases, elasticity of substitution was much closer to one than to zero and therefore that the geometric mean was a more appropriate reflection of consumer behaviour. One of their key findings was that consumers are very responsive to price changes at the elementary aggregate level, the level on which the geometric mean operates. However, the study went further, finding that even the geometric mean might not fully capture substitution, with some elasticities exceeding one. There is separate evidence, for example, that brand-level elasticity is often more in the one and a half to two range.
Closer to home, also in 2009, the Scottish Government published an overview of evidence on food prices. I hope that this reassures noble Lords that consumers do substitute when prices rise; not necessarily that they substitute all the time, for the geometric mean does not demand that; simply that some people will substitute when an item has risen sharply in price and there is a good substitute.
The CPI deals only with substitution on the elementary aggregate level, the lower level.
Suffice to say that the theory and evidence for consumer substitution is compelling, that the geometric mean is an appropriate method of capturing that behaviour and therefore that the CPI's method of aggregation is superior. That is why the geometric mean is used in the consumer prices index of the United States, Canada, Australia, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, France, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and Austria.'
'[W]hen we looked at this issue as a new Government, we were prompted particularly by the context of a year in which the RPI had been negative. In April 2010, up-rating had been nil for the state earnings-related pension scheme, public sector pensions and all the connected pensions. That is not because inflation for pensioners had been nil but because that is what the RPI said. The RPI was clearly not doing its job then, and that focused our mind on whether it was the right thing. It is true that, on average, the CPI tends to be lower not always, but generally. I have looked at the past 20 years, and in five of those the RPI has been lower than the CPI. That improves the situation in a difficult financial position; I would not pretend that it does not. However, our job is to have an appropriate, stable measure of inflation, and that is what the CPI achieves. Indeed, it is much less volatile. ...'
The relevant statutory provisions
'28. Public service pensions, including those for the civil service, police, the NHS and local government, may be increased in accordance with the rules established under the Pensions (Increase) Act 1971 [("the 1971 Act")]. That Act creates a link between public sector pensions and certain state benefits. The effect is that when benefits are increased to take account of the rise in prices that same rate is used to increase public service pensions.
29. The mechanism works as follows. Section 150(1) obliges the Secretary of State [for Work and Pensions] to review certain sums annually
"in order to determine whether they have retained their value in relation to the general level of prices obtaining in Great Britain estimated in such manner as the Secretary of State thinks fit."
30. Section 150(2) then sets out what the Secretary of State must do if there has been a rise in the general level of prices:
"Where it appears to the Secretary of State that the general level of prices is greater at the end of the period under review than it was at the beginning of that period, he shall lay before Parliament the draft of an uprating order
(a) which increases each of the sums to which sub-section (3) below applies by a percentage not less than the percentage by which the general level of prices is greater at the end of the period than it was at the beginning;
(b) if he considers it appropriate, having regard to the national economic situation and any other matters which he considers relevant, which also increases by such a percentage or percentages as he thinks fit any of the sums mentioned in subsection (1) above, but to which subsection (3) below does not apply; and
(c) stating the amount of any sums which are mentioned in subsection (1) above but which the order does not increase."
31. Section 150(3) then sets out certain benefits in social security legislation, such as the additional state pension. The effect, therefore, is that certain benefits are automatically up-rated in line with the percentage price increase whereas in the case of other benefits there is a discretion whether to give effect to that increase or not, and one of the factors the Secretary of State is required to consider in the latter case is the national economic situation.
32. Section 150(9) provides that the Secretary of State shall make an order in the form of the draft if it is approved by a resolution of each House.
33. Section 189(8) of the 1992 Act provides that an order under section 150 "shall not be made by the Secretary of State without the consent of the Treasury."
34. Where an up-rating order is made under section 150 , section 59(1) of the Social Security Pensions Act 1975 [("the 1975 Act")] then requires the Treasury to make an order applying the same up-rating percentage used for the additional state pension (which is listed at section 150(1)(c) ) to what are described as official state pensions, as defined in the [1971] Act, which include the relevant pension schemes in issue in this case. So far as relevant, section 59(1) states:
"Where by virtue of section 150(1) a direction is given that the sums mentioned in section 150(1)(c) are to be increased by a specified percentage the Minister for the Civil Service shall by order provide that the annual rate of an official pension may if a qualifying condition is satisfied or the pension is a derivative or substituted pension or a relevant injury pension, be increased by the same percentage as that specified in the direction."
35. It is no longer the Minister for the Civil Service who exercises that power, but the Treasury, pursuant to the Transfer of Functions (Minister for the Civil Service & Treasury) Order 1981.
36. Section 59(6) of the 1975 Act provides that an order made under this section has to be made by statutory instrument and shall be laid before both Houses of Parliament after being made.'
The legitimacy of using CPI for up-rating under section 150 of the 1992 Act
Taking account of the national economy when selecting an index under section 150(1)
'Parliament must have conferred the discretion with the intention that it should be used to promote the policy and objects of the Act; the policy and objects of the Act must be determined by construing the Act as a whole, and construction is always a matter of law for the court.'
To similar effect, in Tower Hamlets LBC v Chetnik Developments Ltd [1988] AC 858, 873, Lord Bridge of Harwich said:
'. . . [B]efore deciding whether a discretion has been exercised for good or bad reasons, the court must first construe the enactment by which the discretion is conferred. Some statutory discretions may be so wide that they can, for practical purposes, only be challenged if shown to have been exercised irrationally or in bad faith. But if the purpose which the discretion is intended to serve is clear, the discretion can only be validly exercised for reasons relevant to the achievement of that purpose.'
As Mr Giffin points out, the House of Lords in that case rejected the proposition that, in exercising a discretionary power to refund a mistaken overpayment of rates, the rating authority was entitled to have regard to its financial circumstances or to those of the ratepayer.
What if the effect on the national economy cannot be taken into accout?
'Where the reasons given by a statutory body for taking ... a particular course of action are not mixed and can clearly be disentangled, but where the court is quite satisfied that even though one reason may be bad in law, nevertheless the statutory body would have reached precisely the same decision on the other valid reasons, then this court will not interfere by way of judicial review.'
In Smith v North East Derbyshire PCT [2006] 1 WLR 3315, para 10, (a different) May LJ said this:
'Probability is not enough. The defendants would have to show that the decision would inevitably have been the same and the court must not unconsciously stray from its proper province of reviewing the propriety of the decision making process into the forbidden territory of evaluating the substantial merits of the decision.'
(See also per Keene LJ at [2006] 1 WLR 3315, para 16, as well as Simplex 57 P&CR 306, 327 and 329, and R v Secretary of State for the Environment ex p Brent LBC [1982] QB 593, 646.)
Was the 2011 decision to up-rate by reference to CPI lawful?
(i) CPI did not include mortgage interest and was therefore (a) less volatile than RPI and (b) more representative of many pension-receiving households than RPI;
(ii) CPI did not, unlike RPI, exclude some pension-receiving households, and hence was a better measure for up-rating pensions;
(iii) CPI was used by the Bank of England to measure inflation, and therefore was a better index for section 150 purposes than RPI;
(iv) The equivalent of CPI was used as an inflation measure in many other European countries, and so it was a better measure of inflation than RPI;
(v) CPI was compiled largely by reference to the geometric mean, and therefore was a better measure of changes in prices than RPI, which only used the arithmetic mean;
(vi) CPI was less volatile than RPI, and, unlike RPI, it would not have produced an unrealistic negative inflation rate for the year to September 2009.
(i) The Secretary of State's senior policy adviser on up-rating issues considered that CPI was the more appropriate index to use for up-rating for reasons which were purely related to the inherent advantages of CPI as set out in para 74 above;
(ii) The Director of Public Spending at the Treasury took the same view for the same reasons;
(iii) The June 2010 correspondence shows that the Secretary of State also took that view for at least some of those reasons;
(iv) Perhaps of particular significance, given that the decision was ultimately that of the Secretary of State and these were contemporaneous public statements, the DWP Ministers in the Lords and the Commons also were of that view;
(v) none of the reasons which supported this view (as set out in para 74) could be said to be illogical or unreasonable;
(vi) the Secretary of State was not provided with a single reason to reject CPI and stick with RPI, save (presumably) that RPI had consistently been the index by reference to which up-rating had taken place over the previous twenty years or more.
Disposal
Lord Justice Maurice Kay:
Lord Justice Sullivan: