[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions >> Hooper & Anor v Oates [2013] EWCA Civ 91 (20 February 2013) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWCA/Civ/2013/91.html Cite as: [2013] 3 All ER 211, [2014] Ch 287, [2013] 1 EGLR 93, [2013] WLR(D) 72, [2013] 9 EG 93, [2014] 2 WLR 743, [2013] 1 P &CR DG22, [2013] EWCA Civ 91, [2014] 1 CH 287, [2013] 16 EG 108 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Buy ICLR report: [2014] Ch 287] [View ICLR summary: [2013] WLR(D) 72] [Buy ICLR report: [2014] 2 WLR 743] [Help]
ON APPEAL FROM THE MANCHESTER COUNTY COURT
MR RECORDER KHAN
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
LORD JUSTICE LEVESON
and
LORD JUSTICE TOULSON
____________________
(1) STEPHEN JOHN HOOPER (2) LINDA ANNE HOOPER |
Claimants Respondents |
|
- and - |
||
BEVERLEY CHARLES OATES |
Defendant Appellant |
____________________
Philip Flower (instructed by Harold G Walker) for the Respondents
Hearing date: 22 January 2013
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Lord Justice Lloyd:
Introduction and summary
History of the case and essential facts
"The estimated amount for which a property should exchange at the date of valuation between a willing buyer and a willing seller in an arms length transaction after proper marketing wherein the parties each acted knowledgeably, prudently and without compulsion."
The judgment below
"It seems to me that I should depart from the general rule. I recognise that in doing so I am making a judgment as to a possible future event, namely that the value of the property may increase. However, by making the decision that I make I bring an end to the litigation and bring certainty to the parties. The alternatives to that approach would be either to calculate the damages at the date of breach, which would seem not to accurately reflect the compensatory rule, or, alternatively, postpone until an actual sale, if a sale were ever made, which it seems to me would not be in the parties' interests, certainly not in the interests of Mr and Mrs Hooper. There has to be fairness and justice to both Mr and Mrs Hooper and Mr Oates. It seems to me that it is difficult for Mr Oates to argue that there is unfairness to him in circumstances when it is his failure that has caused these difficulties. The Hoopers, in circumstances in which they are not at fault, are, for want of a better expression, nursing a significant loss."
Discussion
"The normal measure of damages is the contract price less the market price at the contractual time fixed for completion."
The author draws an analogy with the sale of goods.
"The normal rule is that damages should be assessed as of the time of breach. However, the rule is applied with a good deal of flexibility, in particular when the claimant has deferred reacting to the breach for a good reason. The rule is thus closely linked to the question of mitigation and will be considered in that context."
"The general rule is that damages for breach of contract should be assessed as at the date when the cause of action rose, viz. the date of the breach (which rule usually applies where substitute performance is readily available in the market) 'but this is not an absolute rule: if to follow it would give rise to injustice the court has power to fix such other date as may be appropriate in the circumstances'."
"50(1) Where the buyer wrongfully neglects or refuses to accept and pay for the goods, the seller may maintain an action against him for damages for non-acceptance.
(2) The measure of damages is the estimated loss directly and naturally resulting, in the ordinary course of events, from the buyer's breach of contract.
(3) Where there is an available market for the goods in question the measure of damages is prima facie to be ascertained by the difference between the contract price and the market or current price at the time or times when the goods ought to have been accepted or (if no time was fixed for acceptance) at the time of the refusal to accept."
"This would seem to be on the ground that the resale price affords good evidence of the market price, and there is no suggestion in these cases awarding the difference between the contract price and the resale price that the latter differed at all from the market price."
"The general principle for the assessment of damages is compensatory, i.e. that the innocent party is to be placed, so far as money can do so, in the same position as if the contract had been performed. Where the contract is one of sale, this principle normally leads to assessment of damages as at the date of the breach, a principle recognised and embodied in section 51 of the Sale of Goods Act 1893. But this is not an absolute rule; if to follow it would give rise to injustice, the court has power to fix such other date as may be appropriate in the circumstances.
In cases where a breach of a contract for sale has occurred, and the innocent party reasonably continues to try to have the contract completed, it would to me appear more logical and just rather than tie him to the date of the original breach, to assess damages as at the date when (otherwise than by his default) the contract is lost. Support for this approach is to be found in the cases. In Ogle v Earl Vane (1867) LR 2 QB 275, LR 3 QB 272, the date was fixed by reference to the time when the innocent party, acting reasonably, went into the market; in Hickman v Haynes (1875) LR 10 CP 598, at a reasonable time after the last request of the defendants (the buyers) to withhold delivery. In Radford v De Froberville, [1977] 1 W.L.R. 1262, where the defendant had covenanted to build a wall, damages were held measurable as at the date of the hearing rather than at the date of the defendant's breach, unless the plaintiff ought reasonably to have mitigated the breach at an earlier date.
In the present case if it is accepted, as I would accept, that the vendors acted reasonably in pursuing the remedy of specific performance, the date on which that remedy became aborted (not by the vendors' fault) should logically be fixed as the date on which damages should be assessed."
"If it stood alone, it would be logical in my view to take into account in estimating the plaintiff's loss any relevant facts proved or admitted before the court down to the date when the court by order actually quantifies the damages, whatever their respective dates. The general rule does not require the court to close its eyes to matters occurring after the breach of contract or after the commencement of the action or even after a judgment has declared the defendant's liability without quantifying it, if they would enable the court to fix the plaintiff's actual loss more accurately."
"For my part I do not think that Lord Wilberforce was seeking to lay down a rigid rule that must inevitably apply to the sort of case here under scrutiny. I mean a case where there is a contract for the sale or for a lease of immovable property. The purchaser or lessee refuses or persistently fails to complete the transaction. The innocent vendor or lessor after a time elects not to press for specific performance but to be content with damages at law. Subsequently, without depreciatory haste or imprudent tarrying, he sells or lets the property to someone else, thus fixing the amount of his actual loss once for all. If the new sale or letting itself constitutes, or is co-incident in date with, the innocent party's election, the present question will not arise, and the case will in principle be similar to Ogle v Earl Vane (1868) LR 3 QB 272 cited by Lord Wilberforce. But even if he necessarily or properly takes some further time to resell or relet, why should not either side be entitled to rely on the actual result for the purpose of ascertaining the loss? Two reasons, in addition to the importance of the general principle as laid down by Mr Baron Parke, lead me to the conclusion that either party is entitled to rely on it. First it is well settled that the innocent party can recover no greater damages for breach of contract than the loss he would have sustained had he acted reasonably to avoid or reduce loss. In that sense he is said to have a duty to take reasonable steps to mitigate his loss. It is likewise settled law that the defaulting party is liable for the additional damage suffered should the innocent party's reasonable steps to mitigate the loss eventually aggravate it. Those rules seem to me to require that the defendant have the benefit of successful mitigation when damages come to be assessed. No authority has been cited to suggest that the victim of a breach of contract can cut short his duty to mitigate his loss by the mere commencement of an action for damages, and in my view it would be unreasonable to allow him to do so. Mr Swingland indeed complains that if facts subsequent to the writ are once allowed in, the suit becomes a gamble for the plaintiff. He may fail to prove actual loss as at the date of trial and so lose his costs though he began the action quite reasonably. I do not think such cases would be common, and in my view any apparent injustice could be obviated by the exercise of judicial discretion over costs."
"41. The broad principle deducible from the Elena D'Amico and the authorities there considered is that where a contract is discharged by reason of one party's breach, and that party's unperformed obligation is of a kind for which there exists an available market in which the innocent party could obtain a substitute contract, the innocent party's loss will ordinarily be measured by the extent to which his financial position would be worse under the substitute contract than under the original contract.
42. The rationale is that in such a situation that measure represents the loss which may fairly and reasonably be considered as arising naturally, i.e. according to the usual course of things, from the breach of contract (Hadley v Baxendale, (1854) 9 Exch 341 at p.354). It is fair and reasonable because it reflects the wrong for which the guilty party has been responsible and the resulting financial disadvantage to the innocent party at the time of the breach. The guilty party has been responsible for depriving the innocent party of the benefit of performance under the original contract (and the innocent party is simultaneously released from his own unperformed obligations). The availability of a substitute market enables a market valuation to be made of what the innocent party has lost, and a line thereby to be drawn under the transaction. Whether the innocent party thereafter in fact enters into a substitute contract is a separate matter. He has, in effect, a second choice whether to enter the market similar to the choice which first existed at the time of the original contract, but at the new prevailing rate instead of the contract rate (the difference being the basis of the normal measure of damages). The option to stay out of the market arises from the breach, but it does not follow that there is a causal nexus between the breach and a decision by the innocent party to stay out of the market, so as to make the guilty party responsible for that decision and its consequences. The guilty party is not liable to the innocent party for the effect of market changes occurring after the innocent party has had a free choice whether to re-enter the market, nor is the innocent party required to give credit to the guilty party for any subsequent market movement in favour of the innocent party."
Lord Justice Leveson
Lord Justice Toulson