[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
United Kingdom Competition Appeals Tribunal |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> United Kingdom Competition Appeals Tribunal >> Barclays Bank Plc v Competition Commission & Ors [2009] CAT 27 (16 October 2009) URL: http://www.bailii.org/uk/cases/CAT/2009/27.html Cite as: [2009] Comp AR 381, [2009] CAT 27 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
Neutral Citation [2009] CAT 27
Case No: 1109/6/809
IN THE COMPETITION
APPEAL TRIBUNAL
Victoria House
Bloomsbury Place
London WC1A 2EB
16th October 2009
BETWEEN:
Applicant
Interveners
Respondent
Intervener
_______________________________________________________________________
______________________________________________
Mr Thomas Sharpe QC and Mr Matthew Cook (instructed by Clifford Chance LLP) appeared on behalf of Barclays Bank Plc
Ms Helen Davies QC and Miss Kelyn Bacon (instructed by Herbert Smith LLP) appeared on behalf of Lloyds Banking Group
Mr Paul Lasok QC and Mr Tim Ward (instructed by DLA Piper UK LLP) appeared on behalf of Shop Direct Group Financial Services Ltd
Mr John Swift QC, Ms Kassie Smith and Ms Elisa Holmes (instructed by the Treasury Solicitor) appeared on behalf of the Competition Commission
Mr Mark Hoskins QC and Ms Marie Demetriou were instructed by and appeared on behalf of the Financial Services Authority
I. INTRODUCTION
"…a prohibition on distributors and intermediaries from selling PPI to their credit customers within seven days of a credit sale, unless the customer had proactively returned to the seller at least 24 hours after the credit sale; a prohibition on selling single-premium PPI policies (where the premium is paid in one upfront payment, generally by adding the premium to the credit borrowed); a requirement on retail PPI distributors to offer retail PPI separately when they also offer retail PPI bundled with merchandise cover; and several requirements to provide specified information in marketing materials, at the points of sale of credit and PPI, and each year after the PPI policy has entered into force."
II. THE LAW
The Commission's tasks
"…decide whether any feature, or combination of features, of each relevant market prevents, restricts or distorts competition in connection with the supply or acquisition of any goods or services in the United Kingdom or a part of the United Kingdom." (Section 134(1)).
By subsection (2) an affirmative decision means that, for the purposes of the Act there is an AEC.
"The Commission shall, if it has decided on a market investigation reference that there is an adverse effect on competition, decide the following additional questions...
(a) whether action should be taken by it under section 138 for the purpose of remedying, mitigating or preventing the adverse effect on competition concerned or any detrimental effect on customers so far as it has resulted from, or may be expected to result from, the adverse effect on competition;
(b) whether it should recommend the taking of action by others for the purposes of remedying, mitigating or preventing the adverse effect on competition concerned or any detrimental effect on customers so far as it has resulted from, or may be expected to result from, the adverse effect on competition; and
(c) in either case, if action should be taken, what action should be taken and what is to be remedied, mitigated or prevented."
In the present case, the Commission resolved both to take action itself under section 138 and to recommend the taking of action by others (the FSA).
"For the purposes of this Part, in relation to a market investigation reference, there is a detrimental effect on customers if there is a detrimental effect on customers or future customers in the form of...
(a) higher prices, lower quality or less choice of goods or services in any market in the United Kingdom (whether or not the market to which the feature or features concerned relate); or
(b) less innovation in relation to such goods or services."
The effect of that definition is to restrict the class of effects qualifying as detrimental to matters of price, quality, choice and innovation. It does not however mean that there is always a detrimental effect on customers merely because, for example, prices are higher.
"In deciding the questions mentioned in subsection (4), the Commission shall, in particular, have regard to the need to achieve as comprehensive a solution as is reasonable and practicable to the adverse effect on competition and any detrimental effects on customers so far as resulting from the adverse effect on competition."
"The Commission shall, in relation to each adverse effect on competition, take such action under section 159 or 161 as it considers to be reasonable and practicable...
(a) to remedy, mitigate or prevent the adverse effect on competition concerned; and
(b) to remedy, mitigate or prevent any detrimental effects on customers so far as they have resulted from, or may be expected to result from, the adverse effect on competition."
Sections 159 and 161 empower the Commission to impose remedies either by the acceptance of undertakings or the making of Orders. In the present case the Commission decided to impose its remedies by making Orders.
"Although the Commission must always consider the appropriateness of any remedial action, it is unlikely that the Commission, having decided that there is an adverse effect on competition, will decide that there is no case for remedial action, at least before it has given attention to any relevant customer benefits that may accrue from the market features. Examples of exceptional circumstances where the Commission may conclude that no action is appropriate might be where the costs of any practicable remedy seem disproportionate in the light of the size of the relevant market…"
Under the sub-heading "The Cost of remedies and proportionality", paragraph 4.10 states:
"The Commission must have regard to the reasonableness of any remedy and will aim to ensure that no remedy is disproportionate in relation to the adverse effect on competition and any adverse effects on customers. Part of its consideration will include an assessment of the costs of implementing a remedy, for example in disbanding or modifying a distribution system; and the costs of complying with a remedy, for example, providing the OFT with periodic information on prices or margins. However, the Commission must consider the wider picture. Adverse effects on competition are likely to result in a cost or disadvantage to the UK economy in general and customers in particular. Where significant, these costs might usually be expected to outweigh the costs incurred by any person on whom remedies are imposed."
"The Court has consistently held that the principle of proportionality is one of the general principles of Community law. By virtue of that principle, the lawfulness of the prohibition of an economic activity is subject to the condition that the prohibitory measures are appropriate and necessary in order to achieve the objectives legitimately pursued by the legislation in question; when there is a choice between several appropriate measures recourse must be had to the least onerous, and the disadvantages caused must not be disproportionate to the aims pursued."
Although this principle is expressed in terms of a restraint on legislation, no- one before us suggested that it was not equally applicable to administrative action.
"137. That passage identifies the main aspects of the principles. These are that the measure: (1) must be effective to achieve the legitimate aim in question (appropriate), (2) must be no more onerous than is required to achieve that aim (necessary), (3) must be the least onerous, if there is a choice of equally effective measures, and (4) in any event must not produce adverse effects which are disproportionate to the aim pursued.
138. The first thing to note is that the application of these principles is not an exact science: many questions of judgment and appraisal are likely to arise at each stage of the Commission's consideration of these matters. This is perhaps most obviously the case when it comes to the balancing exercise between the (achievable) aims of the proposed measure on the one side, and any adverse effects it may produce on the other side. In resolving these questions the Commission clearly has a wide margin of appreciation, with the exercise of which a court will be very slow to interfere in an application for judicial review.
139. That margin of appreciation extends to the methodology which the Commission decides to use in order to investigate and estimate the various factors which fall to be considered in a proportionality analysis (and indeed in its determination of the statutory questions of comprehensiveness, reasonableness and practicability). There is nothing in the governing legislation, or in the general law, which requires the Commission to follow any particular formal procedure or methodology when it comes to consider the effectiveness of a possible remedy, or its relevant costs, adverse effects and benefits. … The Commission can tailor its investigation of any specific factor to the circumstances of the case and follow such procedures as it considers appropriate. In this regard it may well be sensible for the Commission to apply a "double proportionality approach": for example, the more important a particular factor seems likely to be in the overall proportionality assessment, or the more intrusive, uncertain in its effect, or wide-reaching a proposed remedy is likely to prove, the more detailed or deeper the investigation of the factor in question may need to be. Ultimately the Commission must do what is necessary to put itself into a position properly to decide the statutory questions. As the Commission itself accepts, this includes examining and taking account of relevant considerations, such as the effectiveness of the remedy, the time period within which it will achieve its aim, and the extent of any adverse effects that may flow from its implementation.
…
143. It is worth noting that element (1) of the proportionality principles is closely linked to element (4) (see paragraph [137] above). In other words it is necessary to know what the measure is expected to be able to achieve in terms of an aim, before one can sensibly assess whether that aim is proportionate to any adverse effects of the measure. The proportionality of a measure cannot be assessed by reference to an aim which the measure is not able to achieve."
The task of the Tribunal
"… the question for the court is, did the [decision-maker] ask himself the right question and take reasonable steps to acquaint himself with the relevant information to enable him to answer it correctly?"
In Mahon v. Air New Zealand Limited [1984] AC 808 at 820G, Lord Diplock said that an investigative decision-maker:
"must base his decision upon evidence that has some probative value …"
In Office of Fair Trading v. IBA Healthcare Limited [2004] EWCA Civ 142 Carnwath LJ said, speaking of this Tribunal when reviewing a factual judgment of the OFT, at paragraph 93:
"there is no doubt that the court is entitled to enquire whether there was adequate material to support [the relevant] conclusion."
"The limit of this indulgence is reached where findings are based on no satisfactory evidence. It is one thing to weigh conflicting evidence which might justify a conclusion either way, or to evaluate evidence wrongly. It is another thing altogether to make insupportable findings. This is an abuse of power and may cause grave injustice. At this point, therefore, the court is disposed to intervene.
'No evidence' does not mean only a total dearth of evidence. It extends to any case where the evidence, taken as a whole, is not reasonably capable of supporting the finding; or where, in other words, no tribunal could reasonably reach that conclusion on the evidence. This 'no evidence' principle clearly has something in common with the principle that perverse or unreasonable action is unauthorised and ultra vires. "
"Where the reasons given by a statutory body for taking or not taking a particular course of action are not mixed and can clearly be disentangled, but where the court is quite satisfied that even though one reason may be bad in law, nevertheless the statutory body would have reached precisely the same decision on the other valid reasons, this court will not interfere by way of judicial review. In such a case, looked at realistically and with justice, such a decision of such a body ought not to be disturbed.
…
Another approach to the same problem in such circumstances, which really reflects the same thinking is this: the grant of what may be the appropriate remedies in an application for judicial review is a matter for the discretion of this court. Where one is satisfied that although a reason relied on by a statutory body may not properly be described as insubstantial, nevertheless even without it the statutory body would have been bound to come to precisely the same conclusion on valid grounds, then it would be wrong for this court to exercise its discretion to strike down, in one way or another, that body's conclusion."
III. THE GROUNDS OF BARCLAYS' APPLICATION
IV. GROUND 4 - RELEVANT MARKET ANALYSIS
"We conclude that, for all types of PPI policies, the relevant product market is the sale of PPI to an individual distributor's, or intermediary's, credit customers by that distributor or intermediary."
At R3.2 the Commission described that conclusion as having taken account of all the evidence available, and as being consistent with the evidence in the round.
Distributor |
A company which sells PPI alongside its own credit product. |
Intermediary | An intermediary is a third party through whom consumers identify a suitable type of PPI policy, whether with or without an associated credit product. Examples of intermediaries are brokers and independent financial advisors. |
IP | Income protection insurance. Provides protection in the event that one has to provide care for a spouse, partner, parent or child full time; hospitalisation; accident; sickness (disability); and involuntary unemployment. |
SSNIP test | Small but significant non-transitory increase in price test (also known as the hypothetical monopolist test). |
Stand-alone PPI | PPI that is not sold alongside an underlying credit product. |
Stand-alone provider | A company that provides stand-alone PPI. |
"The reason for this is that we found that the competitive constraints being imposed on distributors and intermediaries by other providers of PPI, by providers of short-term IP, by providers of other types of insurance products and by consumers choosing not to purchase PPI were not sufficiently strong to warrant a wider product market. Further, we found that the constraint on PPI prices as a result of the complementary demand relationship with credit was not sufficiently strong to warrant a wider systems market including credit and PPI.
For stand-alone PPI and stand-alone short-term IP providers, we concluded that they competed to win customers from across the range of PPI providers, both those who offer PPI in combination with credit and those who offer it on a stand-alone basis. As such, the relevant markets are asymmetric. We concluded that stand-alone providers are constrained by competition with distributors, but the scale of substitution from distributors to stand-alone providers is insufficient to competitively constrain the distributors. Stand-alone providers therefore operate in a wider economic market including all providers of PPI."
"( The internal documents and oral evidence that we received from the distributors indicated that the responsiveness of the demand for distributors' PPI policies to changes in the price of those policies was low.
( Our assessment of the evidence on consumers' search and switching patterns indicated that relatively few consumers shop around for PPI policies or combinations of PPI and credit.
( The result of the CC GfK NOP 2008 survey of purchasers of PPI policies indicated that limited numbers of purchasers of PPI policies compared two or more PPI policies before their purchase. Our analysis of the results of this survey indicated that changes in the price of a PPI policy would result in a relatively small change in the sales of that policy.
( Our analysis of the distributors' sales data showed that a demand for a distributor's PPI policies was not as responsive to changes in its PPI price as we would expect in a competitive market.
( There was little evidence of competition on non-price factors.
( The high margins earned on PPI policies indicated that the responsiveness of demand for PPI to changes in PPI prices was low."
The summary which we have recited is underpinned in the Report by detailed and painstaking analysis of each element of that reasoning, cross-referenced to the evidence gathered by the Commission upon which it was based.
"The Commission's analysis of the relevant market(s) and the extent of the competition problems which existed in the markets which the Commission found to exist were flawed by its failure to take account of relevant considerations."
Ground 4 is then subdivided under five sub-headings, each of which we address below. They are however preceded by the assertion that the Commission should, as it had done in its 2003 inquiry into the supply of extended warranties on domestic electrical goods, have adopted a broader market definition, for the reasons given in that report. There is, in our view, nothing in this point. The appropriate market definition in any particular investigation is, as paragraph 91 of the Notice of Application acknowledges, highly fact specific. The fact that, on different (albeit loosely analogous) facts, the Commission reached a different view in another investigation says nothing about the lawfulness of the process whereby the Commission arrived at its narrow market definition in the present case.
i) a reduction in profitability;
ii) falling penetration rates;
iii) increased claim rates on PPI insurance;
iv) an overall contraction in the PPI market.
i) an incorrect application of the SSNIP test;
ii) an incorrect application of the "cellophane fallacy"; and
iii) a failure to take into account evidence supportive of a wider market definition.
Woven into the second and third of those sub-sections was a circularity argument, to the effect that the Commission wrongly used its competition analysis to support its market definition analysis, when the former was to a significant extent the product of the latter.
i) a sufficient number of consumers searched for credit and PPI together, to justify a system market definition;
ii) the Commission wrongly assumed that evidence of high termination rates did not imply a high level of switching between PPI policies;
iii) the Commission assumed a lack of innovation (and therefore of non-price competition) without identifying any benchmark as the basis for that value judgment;
iv) the Commission's finding that high margins were earned on PPI sales was vitiated by failure to consider recent market information and by a circular failure to consider the extent to which profits were applied in reducing credit prices.
Conclusions on Ground 4
V. GROUND 1
"The Commission failed to take account of considerations which are relevant to the proportionality of the POSP."
On analysis, this ground breaks down into two distinct sub-headings, the first of which has two related elements to it. Under the first sub-heading, the allegation is that the Commission entirely failed to analyse or identify the extent of benefits that would arise from its proposed package of remedies. Rather, it is said that the Commission simply analysed the extent of the detriment to consumers constituted by the AEC which it hoped would be put right by the remedy package. The Commission thereby, it is said, failed to ask itself to what extent its package of remedies could be expected to remedy the AEC.
Failure to identify the extent of the benefits to be derived from the remedies package
"… it is necessary to know what the measure is expected to achieve in terms of an aim, before one can sensibly assess whether that aim is proportionate to any adverse effects of the measure. The proportionality of a measure cannot be assessed by reference to an aim which the measure is not able to achieve."
"The Commission also put forward no analysis which suggested that it expected its remedy to eradicate the entire consumer detriment resulting from the AEC …" (Notice of Application paragraph 32.)
i) a failure by distributors and intermediaries actively to seek to win customers by using the price or quality of their PPI policies as a competitive variable;
ii) barriers to search for consumers who wish to compare PPI policies, whether or not combined with credit;
iii) barriers to consumers who wish to switch from one PPI policy to a policy supplied by an alternative provider, or to alternative types of insurance including, in particular, the excessive cost of switching out of a single premium policy; and
iv) "the sale of PPI at the point of sale by credit providers further restricts the extent to which other providers can compete effectively" (paragraph 5.144(d)).
That last element, known as the point of sale advantage or "POSA", is given detailed analysis at R:5.88 to R:5.119, which deserve reading in full.
i) the Commission's framework for its task of assessing remedies;
ii) a summary of submissions by contributors to the inquiry relevant to the remedy assessment;
iii) a detailed analysis of each element to be included in the proposed package, including the Commission's views on responses to them when published as provisional proposals;
iv) a description of remedies which the Commission decided not to implement, together with reasons;
v) an identification of relevant customer benefits arising from the AEC (as defined in section 134(8));
vi) an assessment of the overall effectiveness and proportionality of the remedies package, including an analysis of the question whether to modify the package for the purpose of preserving relevant customer benefits;
vii) a consideration of issues relating to implementation;
viii) a summary.
"In considering whether a remedy is reasonable and practicable, we should consider its implementation costs … We should endeavour to minimise any ongoing compliance costs to the parties, provided that the effectiveness of the remedy is not reduced … However, we should balance those costs against the benefit to the UK economy and to consumers in particular.
We should also take account of the proportionality of any remedies or package of remedies in relation to the AEC and any resulting detrimental effect on consumers. If we are choosing between two remedies or packages of remedies which we consider would be equally effective, we will choose that which imposes the least cost or that is the least restrictive …."
"(a) a prohibition on selling PPI at the credit point of sale and within a fixed time period of the credit sale ('the point-of-sale prohibition');
(b) an obligation to provide a personal PPI quote ('the personal PPI quote');
(c) an obligation to provide information about the cost of PPI and 'key messages' in PPI marketing material ('information provision in marketing material');
(d) an obligation to provide information to the OFT and the FSA for monitoring and publication; and an obligation to provide information about claims ratios to any party on request ('provision of information to third parties');
(e) a recommendation to the FSA that it uses the information provided to it under this obligation to populate its PPI price comparison tables;
(f) an obligation to offer retail PPI separately from merchandise cover where both are offered together as a bundled product ('unbundling retail PPI from merchandise cover');
(g) a prohibition on the selling of single-premium PPI policies ('single premium prohibition'); and
(h) an obligation to provide an annual statement of PPI cost and a reminder of the consumer's right to cancel ('annual statement')."
"Aspects of the point-of-sale advantage would not be addressed;" (R:10.39(a)).
"We agree that this remedy will not entirely remove all aspects of the incumbency advantage enjoyed by distributors. However, we do not think that we need to remove all incumbency advantages of distributors in order effectively to remedy this aspect of the AEC.
We acknowledge that – as with any intervention aimed at enhancing competition – there is a risk that this element of the remedies package will not generate the changes in behaviour necessary fully to address the AEC."
There follows, at R:10.43-45 a series of detailed reasons why, in the Commission's view, the POSP would nonetheless substantially contribute to the remedying of the AEC.
"The aim of our remedies package, in accordance with the aims of the market investigation regime, is to ensure that where market features lead to consumer detriment, these are addressed thereby safeguarding the overriding public interest in markets working well for consumers through the promotion of vigorous competition;" (R:10.66).
"that a prohibition on selling PPI at the credit point of sale was a necessary part of the remedies package that we have identified as a comprehensive, reasonable and practicable solution to the AEC that we found."
The Commission added that the POSP would complement the other elements in the remedies package.
"We concluded that the point-of-sale advantage contributed significantly to the AEC that we had identified. Given the severity of the competition problems and the scale of the resultant consumer detriment, we concluded that it was necessary to introduce a remedies package that would lead to a new, more competitive, market structure." (R:10.72).
"We acknowledge that the point-of-sale prohibition will represent a very significant change to current PPI sales practices and noted strenuous opposition by the parties to this element of our remedies package. We considered carefully the extent to which any of the arguments put to us regarding the alleged risk of the point-of-sale prohibition were well-founded and accordingly whether we should revisit our provisional decision on this element of the remedies package. However, we concluded that this prohibition, taken together with other elements of our remedies package, was the only effective way to address key aspects of the AEC that we found." (R:10.73).
"In view of the scale of the competition issues and resultant consumer detriment that we have identified we consider that imposition of some cost on distributors and intermediaries was justified in order to achieve an effective remedy to the AEC. Moreover, we were confident that our remedies package would be an effective and proportionate solution to the very significant competition problems and resulting consumer detriment that we had identified." (R:10.78).
We decided therefore that a prohibition on selling PPI at the credit point of sale was a necessary part of the remedies package in order to achieve as comprehensive a solution to the AEC and resultant consumer detriment as was reasonable and practicable." (R:10.79).
"We concluded that these lower prices were a direct result of the distributors' anticipation of high profit margins on PPI. Lower credit prices are therefore a direct result of the features of PPI that lead to an AEC in the markets for PPI."
This cross-subsidisation has come to be known as the "waterbed effect".
"We also noted that the recent evaluation of the Extended Warranty Order found that while the remedies package put in place following the CC's investigation – comprising information provision at the point of sale, a cooling-off period for 45 days and pro-rata rebates beyond that date – has had a net beneficial effect on consumers, the Order has only resulted in a relatively small reduction in consumer detriment (at £18.6 million a year) compared with an estimated annual detriment at £366 million."
It is evident from this passage that the Commission had well in mind that there was a risk that the benefit of a remedies package to consumers would be substantially less than the detriment to consumers constituted by the AEC which that package was intended to address.
"We considered that this combination of measures, opening up the market to competition and directly addressing search and switching costs, will comprehensively address the AEC that we have found and which results in consumer detriment."
"…the point-of-sale prohibition, which is the most costly to implement, is at the heart of the remedies package. However, based on the information we have seen, we conclude that the ongoing costs on the remedies package we are proposing would be significantly less than the annual consumer detriment we found (see paragraphs 10.494 and 10.496) so that we expect that, over time, the benefits to customers of putting this package in place will substantially outweigh the costs. The evidence we received indicated to us that the proposed package would not increase parties' costs by an amount that was disproportionate to the AEC and related customer detriment we have found."
"We decided that the package of remedies we have set out will provide a comprehensive, reasonable and practicable solution to the AEC that we have identified in a timely manner."
"As with any set of competition-enhancing remedies, we cannot predict exactly how the market will develop. However, we concluded that our remedies will remove barriers for searching and switching and lead to a larger stand-alone market whilst still enabling distributors to offer combinations of credit and PPI and to compete on the terms of the combination as well as of its component parts. We considered that the package of remedies will lead to more active competition for PPI consumers: through more active marketing before the credit sale; in response to increased consumer search just after the credit point of sale; and by encouraging the switching during the life of the credit product. This competition will manifest itself through more PPI advertising and lower prices."
"We decided that the remedies set out in this decision represent as comprehensive a solution to the AEC and resultant consumer detriment that we have identified as is reasonable and practicable, and that this package should not be modified to take account of credit prices being lower than they otherwise might be."
"A measure will be considered not to be proportionate if it is ineffective with respect to its aim, or if its "costs" are disproportionately large in comparison with the mischief at which it is aimed." (Paragraph 131)
Timescale
"We believe that price caps could address the customer detriment of higher prices and we have not been persuaded by the evidence that price caps would have negative impacts on competition. However, we consider that the packages of remedies we have decided to implement will address the AEC that we have identified in a timely manner and we do not have to address the customer detriment shown in higher prices resulting from the AEC. We consider that by addressing the AEC with the package of remedies which we have decided on, this aspect of the customer detriment will also be addressed."
Incremental analysis
VI. GROUND 2
"The Commission concluded that the POSP was justified without any proper evidential basis for this conclusion."
Its focus upon an alleged lack of evidence is to be contrasted with Ground 3, in which the allegation is that the Commission's conduct of the proportionality analysis was flawed by reason of its failure to take account of relevant considerations and/or its taking account of irrelevant considerations. An apparent separation out into distinct grounds of complaints about evidence and, in effect, methodology was not rigorously pursued, either by Barclays or in the arguments of the supporting interveners. In reality, each of Grounds 1, 2 and 3 contained a mixture of allegations of breach of the no evidence rule, the taking into account of irrelevant considerations and the omission of relevant considerations. Furthermore, the grouping of the matters of complaint into each of those three Grounds in the Notice of Application was not strictly adhered to throughout the oral submissions. In this judgment we address, Ground by Ground, the points developed in the order adopted at the hearing, to the extent that there are material differences from the grouping of matters of complaint in the Notice of Application.
i) It recorded evidence from contributors to the investigation suggesting that between 58% and 91% of respondents to consumer surveys valued the convenience of being able to purchase PPI at the credit point of sale (R10.48(a)), together with evidence of experimental research by distributors in the form of pilot schemes, which also suggested substantial reductions in PPI take-up rates when PPI sales were de-coupled in any way from sales of the insured credit (R:10.48(b)-49).
ii) At R:10.50 the Commission expressed its conclusion:
"While we acknowledge that this element of the remedies package reduces the convenience of purchasing PPI at the credit point of sale, we consider that the potential reduction in PPI sales has been overestimated by some parties. By increasing competition and thereby reducing price, we expect our remedies package to lead to an increase in PPI sales that would partially or fully offset a decline from a reduction in convenience."
The Commission then gave reasons for discounting the weight of some of the evidence of reduced take-up rates, and continued:
"To the extent that this measure reduces the convenience for some customers of purchasing PPI compared with buying it at the credit point of sale, we are satisfied that this is both necessary to stimulate competition so as to contribute to remedying the AEC identified and justified in light of the scale of the detriment identified."
iii) At R:10.51 the Commission described aspects of its design of the remedies package which it considered would reduce the risks of any substantial fall in take-up rates, in particular by the requirement for a personal PPI quote so as to reduce the risk that consumers would fail to consider PPI at all due to lack of awareness of it, and in permitting consumers to initiate a PPI purchase by internet or telephone 24 hours after the credit sale, so as to reduce inconvenience.
iv) At R:10.52 the Commission considered an argument that the POSP would reduce the level of credit sales, but decided that, even if it did, it should not amend its proposed remedies package on that ground.
i) Having received evidence uniformly to the effect that by prohibiting the sale of PPI at the point of sale of the associated credit the loss of convenience would cause some reduction in take-up rates, the Commission was, in relation to such a radical and unprecedented remedy as the POSP, obliged to form a properly considered judgment about the extent of that reduction, and about the extent to which it could be expected to be off-set by any increase in demand attributable to lower PPI prices.
ii) Instead of forming any such judgment, or carrying out any, let alone any sufficiently rigorous, analysis of the question, the Commission merely discounted some (but without identifying which) of the evidence of reduced take-up rates, and concluded merely that increased demand would "partially or fully" off-set a decline in take-up rates caused by a reduction in convenience.
iii) The Commission thereby left unresolved the question how big that reduction could be expected to be and how much, on a scale of one to one hundred percent, the off-set from increased demand could be expected to be.
iv) Critically, the Commission then failed to include in the proportionality analysis a significant disadvantage attributable to the POSP as part of the remedies package which it had been unable to exclude as a matter of judgment, thereby vitiating its proportionality analysis.
v) Furthermore, in constructing its models for the purpose (among others) of quantifying the static benefits to be expected from the remedies package and the elimination of the AEC, the Commission assumed a substantial increase in PPI sales, contrary to its judgment at R10.50 that a reduced take-up due to lack of convenience would only be partially or fully off-set by increased demand. It thereby quantified the benefits of the remedies package on the basis of a model which was, in that respect, incompatible with the view which it had already formed as to the potential disadvantage attributable to loss of convenience.
vi) Both Barclays and Lloyds likened this alleged failure to the Commission's failure in the Tesco case to take into account, as a disadvantage attributable to the proposed competition test, the likelihood that refusal of planning permission for enlargements of existing supermarkets would lead to significant unmet demand for groceries by consumers. It was submitted that a loss of convenience would have a similar effect, since many consumers who would have been minded to buy PPI at the credit point of sale (and for whom PPI would represent a real benefit) would be put off by their inability to do so, leaving their need for PPI unmet in the post-remedies market place.
VII. GROUND 3
i) That the Commission modelled theoretical remedies packages rather than the actual package it was proposing.
ii) That the model took no account of costs.
iii) That the model was based upon unjustified assumptions that the remedies would be fully effective and reduce excess PPI profits to zero.
iv) That the model took no account of the negative effect on PPI sales attributable to the loss of the point of sale for convenience.
v) That the model was based upon out of date information.
vi) That the Commission failed to calculate the proper elasticity of demand.
"We therefore considered whether our remedies might be expected to have a positive or negative impact on total consumer welfare. To do this, we considered two different examples: a remedy which increased information such that all consumers were able to search effectively for both credit and PPI before arriving at the point of sale of credit, and a remedy where PPI prices were reduced but there was no increase at all in the amount of searching for PPI before the credit point of sale. These two examples represented the two ends of the spectrum in terms of the potential impact of remedies on consumer search."
The modelling process was applied to MPPI, SMPPI and PLPPI.
i) both system and non-system remedies would be fully effective;
ii) that they would be costless; and
iii) that they would drive the level of excess PPI profits to zero in each case.
It is the use of those assumptions which has led to all but the last two of the criticisms grouped under Ground 3.
(a) The modelling of theoretical remedies packages rather than the proposed remedies package
(b) The Commission's modelling took no account of costs
(c) The assumption that the remedies would be fully effective and reduce excess PPI profits to zero
(d) The modelling took no account of adverse consequences of its remedies package
(e) Modelling based on out of date information
(f) Elasticity of demand
VIII. RETAIL PPI
IX. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
i) We have rejected Ground 4 of Barclays' Notice of Application, with the consequence that the Commission's decision as to the appropriate market definition, and as to the nature and extent of competition in the supply of PPI, is not susceptible to review. There has therefore been no effective challenge to any part of the Commission's findings about the nature or seriousness of the AEC which it has identified.
ii) As to Ground 1, we have concluded that the Commission did, as it was entitled to do, conclude that its proposed remedies package would be substantially effective as a remedy for the AEC which it had identified. We have rejected the challenge based upon a supposed failure to adopt an incremental approach. We have concluded that the Commission failed in its Report to address the question of timescale in sufficient depth, but that this was mainly a failing in expression rather than an underlying deficiency in analysis, which was not on its own material to the decision to impose the POSP.
iii) As to Ground 2, we have concluded that the Commission's failure to take into account the loss of convenience which would flow from the imposition of a POSP in assessing whether it was proportionate to include it in its proposed remedies package was, on its own, a sufficient failure to take into account a material consideration to require the quashing and remission for reconsideration of its decision to impose the POSP.
iv) As to Ground 3, we have concluded that certain aspects of the methodology used by the Commission in the modelling which it employed as a tool for quantification of an aspect of the benefits to be expected from its remedies package were defective so as to be judicially reviewable, but that none of those aspects, viewed individually, would have been material, in the sense that the use of appropriate methodology could have led to a decision not to impose the POSP. Nonetheless the combined effect of those failings, coupled with the self-sufficient failure to take convenience into account in its conduct of the proportionality analysis contribute to our decision that the imposition of the POSP must be quashed and remitted for reconsideration. It follows that any such reconsideration should be carried out in the light of our adverse decisions as to those specific aspects of the modelling methodology.
Mr Justice Briggs | Paul Stoneman | Vindelyn Smith-Hillman |
Charles Dhanowa Registrar |
16 October 2009 |